Fazit – das Wirtschaftsblog

Fazit - das Wirtschaftsblog

Für alle, die’s genau wissen wollen: In diesem Blog blicken wir tiefer in Börsen und andere Märkte - meist mit wissenschaftlicher Hilfe

Public finances at a crossroads

| 4 Lesermeinungen

Most Western governments have stopped pursuing policies of budget consolidation for the time being. This is confirmed by the European Commission’s most recent forecast, and many leading Keynesian economists think it’s a good thing. Most international organisations – if they aren’t calling for new spending programmes – are satisfied with this development as well. Critics appear to be zeroing in on Germany in particular, urging the government to convert the last smidgen of “fiscal space” into more short-term demand and long-term debt. Even though Germany has adopted an expansionary fiscal policy to deal with refugee-related costs, raised investment levels, and increased social benefits, this still isn’t enough according to experts like Joseph Stiglitz, some international organisations, and a good number of prominent policy-makers in other parts of the world. By Ludger Schuknecht

Critics too easily overlook the fact that there are important reasons for continuing to carry out policies that improve the health of public finances. After all, demand requires confidence. Confidence isn’t likely to grow if moving to sound public finances is put off until tomorrow – or if tomorrow is too soon, until kingdom come.

First of all, with some exceptions, most Western economies are in pretty decent shape and unemployment levels are low. Europe’s economy is growing at an above-average rate, and the U.S. economy has been expanding for seven years in a row. There is no convincing evidence of a global shortage in demand, or of a crisis that would call for global stimulus. In Germany, indicators show that the economy is running at full or even excess capacity, so adopting new stimulus programmes here makes no sense at all.

Second, the “fiscal space” – that is, the leeway for additional government spending – that so many people invoke simply does not exist, neither in Germany nor in other countries. Rather, most advanced economies are facing the problem of record debt levels that have surged since the global financial crisis. On average, eurozone countries have seen their debt levels rise by almost half to over 90% of GDP. This figure is even higher in the G7 countries, where average general government debt-to-GDP ratios stand at 120%. The debt ratio in the United States exceeds 100%, and is about 250% in Japan. At the moment, debt ratios in most countries are no longer rising, but they are not going down much either, because very little progress is being made in cutting budget deficits further.

Third, societies around the world – in Germany, in the United States, in Asia – are ageing at a rapid pace. So far, not enough has been done to prepare for this development, either by reforming social benefit programmes, building up financial reserves, or reducing debt. Germany too has a significant sustainability gap and must take care not to fall into complacency. The measures our government adopted in recent years have caused social spending to rise again – the curse of good deeds done during good economic times.

Fourth, how debt reduction affects a country’s economic performance depends very much on the quality of the fiscal measures that are taken. For example, reducing government consumption fosters growth and confidence better than tax hikes do. Here it is important to underscore the fact that government spending as a share of GDP is already extremely high in most Western countries. In Europe, government spending accounts for just under 50% of GDP on average, with markedly higher rates in France and Scandinavia. Germany’s government expenditure ratio stands at just under 45%. East Asia presents a different picture: here, government expenditure makes up just 20‑25% of GDP. Measures to lower spending in the right improve efficiency and cut red tape, thereby boosting the incentives for employment and investment while simultaneously reducing budget deficits.

There are other important arguments for pursuing policies of growth-friendly consolidation and debt reduction. Only these types of policies can ensure that, during the next economic downturn or financial crisis, all countries have enough fiscal leeway to avoid losing the confidence of markets and sliding into another sovereign debt crisis. Sound public finances protect states from having to take emergency measures on an ad hoc basis, which often cut spending in the wrong place, such as investment. They make it possible to carry out long-term strategies that leave enough room to finance programmes and policies to master new challenges, such as the costs of the refugee crisis or the need for extra spending on internal and external security. Strategies like this generate confidence that leads to higher rates of consumption and investment. Economists refer to these developments as “non-Keynesian” effects that counteract the negative impact that consolidation can have on demand.

And this brings us to the issue of the credibility of our politics and institutions. When economists claim that higher spending can deliver a big boost to growth – which then allegedly makes it safe to put off budget consolidation because such measures can pay for themselves – they are being naïve. Politics is never as perfect and manageable as economists may think. Furthermore, such claims cause the general public to develop expectations that cannot be fulfilled: expectations of predictable and equitable economic outcomes, higher incomes and security. In this way, we economists lead policy-makers into a trap of wishful thinking rather than providing recommendations that show them how to make the best of the world as it really is.

Naïveté and disregard also characterise the way in which some economists and policy-makers treat the Stability and Growth Pact, even though this pact constitutes one of the most important institutional pillars of the Economic and Monetary Union. The pact is intended to show governments where the limits to indebtedness lie. But repeated exceptions and special circumstances give the impression that the rules can be applied with almost any outcome. It is deeply regrettable that the European Commission has just decided to delay its decision regarding two countries that have breached deficit limits. This would suggest that it might be better for an independent authority to implement the Stability Pact in order to restore confidence and reinforce expectations for sound public finances.

Sound public finances are also crucial for not preventing the European Central Bank to exit from the unconventional monetary policy it has adopted. Excess government debt means that if the ECB were to curtail its purchases of government bonds or raise interest rates, this could trigger market turbulence and thereby hinder the bank in fulfilling its mandate. Economists refer to this scenario as “fiscal dominance”, and it would cause great harm to Europe, both economically and institutionally. Therefore, a lot is at stake. Public finances are truly at a crossroads.

Ludger Schuknecht is chief economist at Germany’s Federal Ministry of Finance.


4 Lesermeinungen

  1. […] of citizens (see, for example what the Chief economist of the Federal Ministry of Finance (here) or Dijsselbloem, the head of the Euro group (here), have to […]

  2. Gerald Braunberger sagt:

    Was leistet expansive Finanzpolitik? Eine kleine Artikelreihe
    Ich nutze die Gelegenheit, um an eine kleine, bisher drei Beiträge umfassende Artikelreihe aus eigener Feder hinzuweisen, in der expansive Finanzpolitik und Schuldentragfähigkeit anhand von konkreten ökonomischen Modellen betrachtet werden. Hier ist ein Link zum dritten Beitrag, der wiederum Links zu den ersten beiden enthält:

    https://blogs.faz.net/fazit/2016/05/27/extremfall-inflationsspirale-wie-hoch-darf-staatsverschuldung-sein-teil-3-7671/

    Bei Gelegenheit führe ich die kleine Reihe fort.

    Viele Grüße
    gb.

  3. hgebhardt sagt:

    Brüning als Chefökonom des Bundesfinanzministeriums
    Einen fundierten Verriss von Heiner Flassbeck zu diesem Artikel findet man unter dem 24.6.2016 in seinem neuen MAKROSKOP:
    “Politische Empfehlungen gegen jede Vernunft
    Der Chefökonom des Bundesfinanzministeriums, Ludger Schuknecht, beweist in einem Namensbeitrag, dass er grundlegende makroökonomische Zusammenhänge noch nicht einmal im Ansatz verstanden hat. Dass eine Finanzpolitik auf der Basis solcher Empfehlungen in die Katastrophe führt, ist nicht verwunderlich.
    […]
    Um es klar zu sagen: Wenn ein hoher deutscher Beamter solche abstrusen Thesen in die Welt setzt, ist das verantwortungslos. Wenn Bundesminister eine solche „Expertise“ auch nur näherungsweise zur Grundlage ihrer Entscheidungen machen, ist das gemeingefährlich. Wie kann sich ein Europa, das aufgeklärt und modern sein will, solch lächerlichen Argumenten unterwerfen? Dieses Denken ist ein schlimmer Rückfall in die Mikroökomik der Zeit vor dem Zweiten Weltkrieg, die schon einmal großes Unheil mit sich gebracht hat. Das glatte Ausblenden der unbestreitbaren makroökonomischen Zusammenhänge, auf die hier verwiesen wurde, und der Versuch einer Fundierung der Argumentation mit einer These, die weder empirisch noch theoretisch zu halten ist, müsste die Wissenschaft und kritische Medien massiv auf den Plan rufen. Doch beides, das kann man aus dem Ausbleiben heftiger Proteste nach einem solchen Artikel schließen, gibt es in Deutschland nicht mehr.”

  4. […] so „das Vertrauen“ der Bürger wieder hergestellt werden kann (siehe den Chefvolkswirt des BMF hier oder hier den Chef der […]

Kommentare sind deaktiviert.